臥底經濟學家

What makes a good prophecy?

For a forecast to be useful, it is neither necessary nor sufficient that it be accurate — here’s why

A couple of years ago, taking questions on stage in front of a live audience, I was asked to do my duty as an economist and make an economic forecast. But the questioner had a demanding benchmark for what made a good prediction, informing me that the previous keynote speaker at this conference had been a prominent scientist, who warned of a deadly global pandemic. That was in the autumn of 2019. Would my forecast be as good?

I parried the question with two questions of my own: my interlocutor would never hear a more consequential forecast than what he was told in 2019, but had he done anything differently? I knew the answer was no. Why, then, was he so interested in hearing another prediction?

My non-answer was weaselly, yes. But the exchange points to a problem: producers of forecasts frequently give people warnings they ignore, and unless consumers of forecasts are honest with themselves about what they plan to use them for, their demand for a glimpse of the future seems fatuous. Or, to quote George Eliot, “Among all forms of mistake, prophecy is the most gratuitous.”

您已閱讀19%(1084字),剩餘81%(4630字)包含更多重要資訊,訂閱以繼續探索完整內容,並享受更多專屬服務。
版權聲明:本文版權歸FT中文網所有,未經允許任何單位或個人不得轉載,複製或以任何其他方式使用本文全部或部分,侵權必究。
設置字型大小×
最小
較小
默認
較大
最大
分享×